|
|
|
Texts belong to their owners and are placed on a site for acquaintance. |
Absolute Advantage In his 1776 landmark book The Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith attacked the mercantilist assumption that trade is a zero-sum game. Smith argued that countries differ in their ability to produce goods efficiently. In his time, the English, by virtue of their superior manufacturing processes, were the world's most efficient textile manufacturers. Due to the combination of favorable climate, good soils, and accumulated expertise, the French had the world's most efficient wine industry. The English had an absolute advantage in the production of textiles, while the French had an absolute advantage in the production of wine. Thus, a country has an absolute advantage in the production of a product when it is more efficient than any other country in producing it. According to Smith, countries should specialize in the production of goods for which they have an absolute advantage and then trade these goods for the goods produced by other countries. In Smith's time, this suggested that the English should specialize in the production of textiles while the French should specialize in wine. England could get all the wine it needed by selling its textiles to France and buying wine in exchange. Similarly, France could get all the textiles it needed by selling wine to England and buying textiles in exchange. Smith's basic argument is that you should never produce goods at home that you can buy at a lower cost from other countries. Moreover, Smith demonstrates that by specializing in the production of goods in which each has an absolute advantage, both countries benefit by engaging in trade. Consider the effects of trade between Ghana and South Korea.
The production of any good (output) requires resources (inputs) such as
land, labor, and capital. Assume that Ghana and South Korea both have
200 units of resources and that these resources can be used to produce
either rice or cocoa. Imagine that in Ghana it takes 10 resources to produce
one ton of cocoa and 20 resources to produce one ton of rice. Thus, Ghana
could produce 20 tons of cocoa and no rice, 10 tons of rice and no cocoa,
or some combination of rice and cocoa in between these two extremes. The
different combinations that Ghana could produce are represented by the
line GG' in Figure 4.1. This is referred to as Ghana's production possibility
frontier (PPF). Similarly, imagine that in South Korea it takes 40 resources
to produce one ton of cocoa and 10 resources to produce one ton of rice.
Thus, South Korea could produce 5 tons of cocoa and no rice, 20 tons of
rice and no cocoa, or some combination in between these two extremes.
The different combinations available to South Korea are represented by
the line KK' in Figure 4.1, which is South Korea's PPF. Clearly, Ghana
has an absolute advantage in the production of cocoa (more resources are
needed to produce a ton of cocoa in South Korea than in Ghana), and South
Korea has an absolute advantage in the production of rice. By engaging in trade and swapping one ton of cocoa for
one ton of rice, producers in both countries could consume more of both
cocoa and rice. Imagine that Ghana and South Korea swap cocoa and rice
on a one-to-one basis; that is, the price of one ton of cocoa is equal
to the price of one ton of rice. If Ghana decided to export 6 tons of
cocoa to South Korea and import 6 tons of rice in return, its final consumption
after trade would be 14 tons of cocoa and 6 tons of rice. This is four
tons more cocoa than it could have consumed before specialization and
trade and one ton more rice. Similarly, South Korea's final consumption
after trade would be 6 tons of cocoa and 14 tons of rice. This is 3.5
tons more cocoa than it could have consumed before specialization and
trade and 4 tons more rice. Thus, as a result of
specialization and trade, output of both cocoa and rice would be increased,
and consumers in both nations would be able to consume more. Thus, we
can see that trade is a positive-sum game; it produces net gains for all
involved. The Theory of Absolute Advantage
Table 4.1 Absolute Advantage and the Gains from Trade
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
<< Mercantilism
|